Is There A Moral Case for “Buy American”?

with 1 Comment

Eye on America

The most often cited reason we should buy American is its supposed economic benefits. However, buying exclusively within a specific geographic region impoverishes the local economy. Voluntary trade benefits both sides. The broader our trading partners, the greater that benefit.

A second rationale for buying American is well-intentioned but not effective. Perhaps we would be economically better off with global trade, it is argued, but we have an obligation to maintain a high moral standard. We insist on a minimum wage for our workers. We have high safety standards and humane working conditions. We should not reward countries that exploit their own people. These arguments, although emotionally moving, actually hurt the truly needy.

Like playing a sport, working for pay is a skill learned by doing. Imagine the people who can’t get hired at a job paying minimum wage. They have a little or no job history. Their communication skills are inadequate. Their education is incomplete. They are unable to follow instructions and even fail to consistently arrive on time.

Training a new employee is costly, not just in salary, but also in the loss of business from the person’s initial poor service and the time and effort expended by other workers to train and supervise the new worker. All this investment is often wasted when the person doesn’t work out.

Some employees are not worth the wage they want. Some are barely worth an unpaid internship. Many might be worth a salary below minimum wage. If applicants are not worth minimum wage, employers can’t afford to hire them. However, any person hired is given a chance to learn the job skills necessary to command a higher salary. Most minimum wage employees who manage to keep the job get a raise during their first year.

The utopian liberal mindset believes nearly everyone is worth minimum wage and that businesses can produce great profits while paying employees $10 or more an hour. If that were true, you should run such a business! Your generous wage would make it impossible for other employers to hire for less.

Minimum wage employers who don’t make a profit are quickly eliminated from the marketplace. Businesses avoid taking on these risky employees to avoid being part of the failed business graveyard. Minimum wage is one reason why minority teenagers have the highest unemployment rates, now at 43%.

What is true of low-skilled workers in the United States also holds true for much of the developing world’s workforce. They cannot compete on anything other than long hours under difficult conditions. Yet they need the money and are eager to work.

A US-made computer in 1984 cost $5,000 – more than $11,000 in today’s dollars. It had no mouse or hard drive, 512K of main memory and two floppy drives.

Today we buy Dell computers for a fraction of the cost and a thousand times the capabilities. Dell assembles its computers overseas. A worker making 52 cents an hour assembles a Microsoft mouse at the KYE Factory in China. But now a mouse costs $20 instead of $200.

The KYE Factory pay rate includes the price of meals. Responding to criticism, the factory stopped allowing 16- and 17-year-olds to work. But we don’t help them by taking a job choice away. Workers with limited experience and skills don’t have many options. Restricting their choices even more doesn’t help.

What we view as exploitation, others view as an opportunity for advancement. No one is underpaid in a free market. If they had a better choice, they would take it. Most are grateful to have what they consider to be a good paying job.

Even if workers in India started at $5 per day, that wage would improve many people’s standard of living. Any indoor job with the prospect of advancement is better than picking over heaps of garbage in the blazing sun.

At $5 a day ($0.62 an hour), working every weekday the Indian worker would earn $1,300 for the year. An American worker earning 50 times more earns $250 a day ($31.25 an hour), or $65,000 a year. For these Americans to protest shows a heartless disregard for people living in poverty.

Complaining the foreigner’s willingness to work for less is displacing domestic jobs and making employment more difficult equates to someone who earns $3.25 million claiming that workers earning $65,000 are stealing their jobs. Workers earning 50 times more are so much more highly skilled and educated, there is no direct competition of labor. Such highly trained workers should be put to work using their skills, rather than usurping jobs from low-skilled inexperienced workers.

Migrant workers in the United States fare even better than those in India. The minimum wage for an authorized Mexican seasonal agricultural worker in the United States is about $80 a day. Mexico’s minimum wage for low-skilled work is under $5 a day. Earning 16 times as much as they can in their native country is quite an incentive. Studies have found such employment greatly benefits the workers and their families. They compete for the opportunity to return to the job year after year.

Some moral arguments about standards hide an anti-foreigner sentiment. “No one should be forced to work for wages far below our minimum wage” conceals the attitude “No one should be allowed to work for wages far below what I want to receive for the same job.”

We would not want someone earning multiples of what we make prohibiting our employment by supposedly helping us. The true moral response is to treat others as we would want to be treated.

We want to be able to choose to work for a given wage. We don’t want someone else making that choice for us. For those who prefer working for pay over not having the choice to work, that’s the same as wishing there wasn’t a minimum wage.

It speaks highly of us when we affirm the fact they are given the choice to work and reflects poorly on us if we boycott their goods demanding that choice be removed. The next time you encounter a foreign-made good when you use your computer, eat a banana or drink a cup of tea, remember this: You are helping to employ the world’s poor and pull them out of poverty.

Photo by AndYaDontStop used here under Flickr Creative Commons.

Subscribe to Marotta On Money and receive free access to the 1.5 hour video about the countries with the most economic freedom: Where in the World Should I Invest?

Follow David John Marotta:

President, CFP®, AIF®, AAMS®

David John Marotta is the Founder and President of Marotta Wealth Management. He played for the State Department chess team at age 11, graduated from Stanford, taught Computer and Information Science, and still loves math and strategy games. In addition to his financial writing, David is a co-author of The Haunting of Bob Cratchit.

Follow Megan Russell:

Chief Operating Officer, CFP®, APMA®

Megan Russell has worked with Marotta Wealth Management most of her life. She loves to find ways to make the complexities of financial planning accessible to everyone. She is the author of over 800 financial articles and is known for her expertise on tax planning.

One Response

  1. David John Marotta
    |

    No one considers the unintended consequences of trying to protect workers in poor countries by means of tariffs. Recently I read this in an article entitled “The Real Consequences of Raising Tariffs for Bangladesh” by K. William Watson:

    The Obama administration has suspended Bangladesh from the list of poor countries that receive preferential tariff treatment in the United States, citing concerns over workplace safety and inadequate labor laws. The vast majority of imports from Bangladesh will not be affected because apparel goods were already exempt from the program. But some tariffs will go up and the human cost of these new taxes is very real.

    The Wall Street Journal’s coverage of yesterday’s announcement includes this anecdote:

    Higher porcelain duties will put a strain on the business of Ian Zucker, chief executive of 10 Strawberry Street in Denver, who imports dinnerware from Bangladesh for Bloomingdale’s, Wal-Mart and others.

    “After the tariff goes in, I have to raise my prices 20 percent,” he said in an interview. “You think Wal-Mart’s going to say that’s OK?”

    Mr. Zucker said he is likely to turn to China or Sri Lanka for dinnerware products, the making of which is labor-intensive, making countries with low wages especially attractive.

    I wonder if the administration thinks it will get a thank-you card from unemployed Bangladeshi dinnerware makers now that they’re no longer being “exploited” by Western investors looking for low-wage labor.